This article has been reviewed according to Science X's editorial process and policies. Editors have highlighted the following attributes while ensuring the content's credibility:

fact-checked

trusted source

proofread

Prosocial preferences can provide better risk management for smallholder farming communities amid rising climate risks

Prosocial preferences can provide better risk management for smallholder farming communities amid rising climate risks
Overview of the evolutionary game theory model. We illustrate the evolutionary game theory framework developed for this analysis using a simplified network of five households. a Households (represented by circles) are connected via social ties (dashed lines), which govern with whom households share part of their income and whose strategies they may imitate. Household risk management strategies are indicated by color (blue, informal revenue-sharing, S; red, formal insurance, I; purple, combination of revenue-sharing and insurance, C). In any given time step, one household is selected as the focal agent (in time t1, this agent deploys strategy S), and another household is selected as the comparison agent (in this case, this agent deploys strategy I). The focal agent compares the utility of its strategy, ZS(x,t1), given the distribution of strategies deployed across the community, x, at time t1, to that of the comparison agent. b, In this example, the utility of I is substantially higher than that of S, so the focal agent adopts insurance in t2 with high probability. Two more households—deploying strategies C and S—are randomly selected as the focal and comparison agents, respectively. c, Now, the utility of S is substantially less than that of C, so the focal agent does not change strategies. Another focal and comparison agent is selected at random, and this sequence repeats for T time steps. d, The elements that constitute utility evaluation include payoffs (parameterized as πi(x, t)), loss aversion (λ), risk aversion (b), discounting (r) and the social preferences (α and κ). e, Social preferences consist of self-interest, in which the focal agent considers only their own utility and actions; altruism, in which the focal agent considers the utilities of every other agent playing their current strategies; and solidarity, in which the focal agent considers its own utility if other households (represented by light blue nodes) also adopt the same strategy of the focal agent. The degree to which altruism and solidarity are incorporated in utility evaluation is determined by the values of α and κ, respectively. Credit: Nature Sustainability (2024). DOI: 10.1038/s41893-024-01272-3

Research conducted by scientists from IIASA and Princeton University suggests that a combination of insurance subsidies and policies that promote "prosocial preferences"―decision-making preferences that account for community well-being―can help facilitate optimal climate risk management and reduce economic losses.

Smallholder farmers use most of their crops and livestock to feed their own households and usually have few financial protections against the unforeseen costs of climate-induced hazards. As continue to rise, smallholder farms are more likely to experience agricultural losses, resulting from both more frequent and more severe extreme weather events such as flooding, drought, and heat waves.

A new study co-led by Nicolas Choquette-Levy, a postdoctoral associate at Boston University and former participant in the IIASA Young Scientists Summer Program (YSSP), and Matthias Wildemeersch, a researcher in the IIASA Advancing Systems Analysis Program, together with other researchers from Princeton University simulated collective-scale outcomes for smallholder farming communities using economic, risk preference, and drought data from Nepal and Ethiopia. They used a modeling framework based on evolutionary game theory.

The researchers found that communities minimized when farmers implemented both formal (e.g., ) and informal (e.g., revenue sharing and informal lending) risk transfer. The co-existence of multiple risk management strategies effectively shields farmers from extreme outcomes during drought cycles and reduces collective-scale volatility while also protecting farmers against individual risks, for instance, a health shock or an unlucky harvest.

While the social optimum was achieved when farmers implemented both formal and informal risk transfer, self-interested households are unable to uphold this combination in the face of rising climate risk.

"Over the past decades, several governments have piloted insurance programs specifically to help cope with climate-related risks," explains Choquette-Levy.

"While these formal market mechanisms have had some success so far, we were curious about whether they might eventually displace existing informal mechanisms through which farmers already manage risks, such as cooperatives and lending groups. Our research showed that this could become a significant challenge as climate risks get more severe, which will likely drive up insurance premiums."

"That introduces a temptation for some farmers to abandon insurance and rely on the contributions of insured members of the community, which in turn incentivizes insured farmers to leave their cooperative."

However, this can be overcome by prosocial decision-making preferences. Prosociality is a decision-making preference where households value the well-being of others or work in solidarity with their community to create optimal outcomes. In communities with high levels of prosociality, households diversify their risk transfer mechanisms by participating in revenue-sharing and purchasing formal insurance.

The authors found that by cultivating pro-social preferences, governments can make existing insurance subsidies more efficient by addressing both financial and social barriers. In this study, the combination of pairing policies to promote prosocial preferences with insurance subsidies reduced expected farming losses by 26% and saved 5% of community agricultural income through reduced premium subsidies.

Though it might not be realistic to expect high levels of prosocial behavior from a community, even moderate levels of prosociality can lead to outcomes where both formal and informal risk transfers are employed, which is optimal for the community.

"We know that individuals, being farmers, local community leaders, or policymakers, are not entirely self-interested, but also driven by their pro-social preferences," says Wildemeersch.

"We wanted to study the role of these preferences in shaping risk management decisions in farming communities. It is important to account for more realistic ways of decision-making to explain the emergence of cooperative behavior. Fostering prosociality through behavioral interventions can play a crucial role in strengthening the resilience of farming communities against the challenges posed by climate risks."

The findings are published in the journal Nature Sustainability.

More information: Nicolas Choquette-Levy et al, Prosocial preferences improve climate risk management in subsistence farming communities, Nature Sustainability (2024). DOI: 10.1038/s41893-024-01272-3

Citation: Prosocial preferences can provide better risk management for smallholder farming communities amid rising climate risks (2024, February 26) retrieved 28 April 2024 from https://phys.org/news/2024-02-prosocial-smallholder-farming-communities-climate.html
This document is subject to copyright. Apart from any fair dealing for the purpose of private study or research, no part may be reproduced without the written permission. The content is provided for information purposes only.

Explore further

A package of policies can help smallholder farmers adapt to a changing climate

8 shares

Feedback to editors