3Qs: Game theory and global climate talks

November 21, 2014 by John O'neill, Northeastern University

Last week, China and the United States announced an ambitious climate agreement aimed at reducing carbon emissions in both countries, a pledge that marks the first time that China has agreed to stop its growing emissions. Leaders of both nations hope the agreement will lead to a global consensus on emissions reduction, with one senior official in the Obama administration saying that the deal "will signal to countries around the world that this negotiation has serious legs and there is a real chance of this coming together."

We asked Rory Smead, a game theory expert and an assistant professor of philosophy and religion at Northeastern, to examine the agreement's potential effect on the prospect of a global as well as what his research suggests about the possibility of successful negotiations. Two of Smead's colleagues—John Basl, an assistant professor of philosophy, and Ronald Sandler, an associate professor of philosophy—contributed to the following responses.

Is this agreement a cause for optimism regarding worldwide climate policy? What else can be done to progress toward a global deal?

The agreement is cause for some optimism. The U.S. and China are such enormous emitters that a successful global climate agreement could not be accomplished without significant reduction commitments from them, and other countries have been frustrated by the lack of such commitments. Moreover, the U.S. government had been reluctant to make any commitments without China also agreeing to some reduction. So, this is definitely a step in the right direction, but there is a long way to go yet.

Emissions from the rest of the world, including projected future emissions from , will also need to be reduced dramatically. Such reduction may, for many nations, be more difficult than for the U.S. and China, given economic, technological, and political circumstances. The U.S. and China may also need to make even greater reductions in emissions, and further cuts may be harder or more costly than the initial cuts. If, in light of the current agreement, we are unwilling to openly consider further cuts, this could hinder future negotiations over global climate policy.

You and your Northeastern colleagues have studied how game theory can be used in international climate negotiations. How does this research apply to this new agreement?

Our research has suggested that side-agreements between nations can have a positive impact on global negotiations. The fact that the U.S. and China are now committed to reduce emissions means that the global problem is a little easier to solve and could make other negotiations more likely to succeed. However, the reaction from other nations will be crucial. One of the points we have emphasized in our research is the importance of the many smaller parties, particularly still developing nations, in the climate negotiation process. We've argued that agreements between many smaller emitters may be more important for reaching global agreements than agreements between a few large emitters. An agreement between the U.S. and China will not solve problems unless we get broad cooperation across the globe.

In your view, what are the most significant challenges to global climate negotiations with regard to justice and fairness, and does this agreement ease those concerns?

Up to this point, considerations of justice and fairness have been a barrier in . India and China, for example, had argued that the U.S. and other affluent nations had a responsibility to make larger proportional emissions reductions, since we are responsible for more past emissions and have a greater capacity for reducing emissions. However, the U.S. has argued that dramatic reductions on our part without concomitant reductions from other large economies, including developing nations like China, would be unfair with respect to economic competitiveness. This demonstrates that it is possible to find common ground on reductions, without having to settle all of the disagreements about justice and fairness. Moreover, from a global justice perspective, it is important to mitigate as much as possible. The reason is that the poorest populations are also the most exposed to the hazards associated with climate change—e.g. extreme weather events, displacement, and food insecurity—and have the fewest resources to cope with them. This is why addressing climate change is such an important moral issue, and not just an economic and political issue.

Explore further: Climate negotiation as a bargaining game

Related Stories

Climate negotiation as a bargaining game

May 12, 2014

For more than two decades, members of the United Nations have sought to forge an agreement to reduce global greenhouse gas emissions. But so far, these international climate negotiations have had limited success.

EU's total responsibility for global emissions has increased

November 17, 2014

"The Kyoto Protocol has not met the expectations. Currently, global emissions are at a more than 50% higher level than during the Protocol's reference year, 1990. In the light of current trends and the annual increase in ...

Climate agreement to have big impact on China

November 17, 2014

China must make significant investments now to meet the targets of last week's agreement with the United States on greenhouse gas emissions, a senior US official said Monday, predicting a big impact on its economy.

US-China climate pact seen boosting Indian efforts

November 14, 2014

This week's China-U.S. climate agreement between the world's top two polluters puts pressure on India, No. 3 on the list, to become more energy efficient and should encourage investment in renewable energy.

Recommended for you

2 comments

Adjust slider to filter visible comments by rank

Display comments: newest first

teslaberry
4 / 5 (1) Nov 21, 2014
the u.s. governmetn is being used by wall street to rationalize price fixing of the entire electricity market to the benefit of wall street speculators who own and run not only the futures market for electricity ( cue ENRON) but also the market for 'carbon credits'.

these major sources of rigged raqueteering profits can be further legitimized and strengthened by 'international agreeement'. meanwhile. china just doesn't give a rats ass about the u.s. posturing and will give the u.s. plenty of token nonsense platitudes so long as nothign meaningful is asked of it. china has an actual pollution and smog problem they are in the midst of grappling with. not a c02 problem. they need MORE c02 and more development and power. they don't need less. they are a growing nation, not a dying one.
gkam
1 / 5 (3) Nov 21, 2014
Teslaberry is partially correct. But even the Chinese know they need much LESS pollution, and have to switch over to clean power, which they are now doing.

Please sign in to add a comment. Registration is free, and takes less than a minute. Read more

Click here to reset your password.
Sign in to get notified via email when new comments are made.