How 9,000 lists written over 300 years are helping to test theories of economic growth

July 3, 2018 by Louise Walsh, University of Cambridge
How 9,000 lists written over 300 years are helping to test theories of economic growth
Credit: University of Cambridge

The handwritten inventories had lain largely untouched for centuries. Sand used to dry the ink still lay between the pages. Written neatly inside were thousands of lists that might hold the key to an enduring puzzle in economics – does education fuel economic growth?

In 1752, Juliana Schweickherdt, a 50-year-old spinster living in the small Black Forest community of Wildberg, was reprimanded by the local weavers' guild for "weaving cloth and combing wool, counter to the guild ordinance".

When Juliana continued taking jobs reserved for male guild members she was summoned before the guild court and fined the equivalent of one third of a maidservant's annual wages. The entire affair was then recorded neatly
in a ledger.

It was a small act of defiance by today's standards, but it reflects a time when laws in Germany, and elsewhere, regulated people's access to labour markets. The dominance of guilds not only prevented people from using their skills, as in Juliana's case, but also held back even the simplest of industrial innovations.

What makes this detail of Juliana's life so interesting is that it is one among a vast number of observations in a huge database on the lives of southwest German villagers between 1600 and 1900. Built by a team led by Professor Sheilagh Ogilvie in the Faculty of Economics, the database includes , guild ledgers, parish registers, village censuses, tax lists and – the most recent addition – 9,000 handwritten inventories listing over a million personal possessions belonging to ordinary women and men across three centuries.

Ogilvie, who discovered the inventories in the archives of two German communities 30 years ago, believes they may hold the answer to a conundrum that has long puzzled economists: the lack of evidence for a causal link between and a country's growth and development.

"It might sound as if this is a no-brainer," explains Ogilvie. "Education helps us to work more productively, invent better technology, earn more, have fewer children and invest more in them – surely it must be critical for ? But, if you look back through history, there's no evidence that having a high literacy rate made a country industrialise earlier."

She explains that between 1600 and 1900, England had only mediocre literacy rates by European standards, yet its economy grew fast and it was the first country to industrialise. Germany and Scandinavia had excellent literacy rates, but their economies grew slowly and they industrialised late.

"Modern cross-country analyses have also struggled to find evidence that education causes economic growth, even though there is plenty of evidence that growth increases education," she adds.

The inventories Ogilvie is analysing listed the belongings of women and men at marriage, remarriage and death. From badger skins to Bibles, dung barrows to dried apple slices, sewing machines to scarlet bodices – the villagers' entire worldly goods were listed. Inventories of agricultural equipment and craft tools revealed economic activities; ownership of books and education-related objects like pens and slates suggested how people learned.

In addition, tax lists recorded the value of farms, workshops, assets and debts; signatures and people's estimates of their age indicated literacy and numeracy levels; and court records revealed obstacles that stifled industry, like Juliana and her wool-combing.

"Previous studies usually had just one proxy for linking education with economic growth – the presence of schools and printing presses, perhaps, or school enrolment, or the ability to sign names.

This database gives us multiple indicators for the same individuals," she explains. "I began to realise that, for the first time ever, it was possible to link literacy, numeracy, wealth, industriousness, innovative behaviour and participation in the cash economy and credit markets – for individual women and men, rich and poor, over the very long term."

Since 2009, Ogilvie and her team have been building the vast database of material possessions on top of their full demographic reconstruction of the people who lived in these two communities. "We can follow the same people – and their descendants – across 300 years of educational and economic change," she says.

Individual lives have unfolded before their eyes. Stories like that of the man who wanted to grow a new crop – turnips – but was forbidden by the village council because it meant driving his cart to the fields at a different time, threatening others' crops in the communal rotation system.

Or the young weaver's wife Magdalena Schöttlin fined 11 days' wages for wearing an "excessively large neckerchief ... above her station". Or the 24-year-olds Ana Regina and Magdalena Riethmüllerin who were chastised in 1707 for reading books instead of listening to the pastor's sermon. "This tells us that they were continuing to develop their reading skills at least a decade after leaving school," explains Ogilvie.

It would be easy to focus on these stories – the aspirations and tragedies, the societal norms and individual rebellions, the possessions precious and prosaic – but, says Ogilvie, now that the data-gathering phase of the project is complete, "it's time to ask the big questions".

One way to look at whether education causes economic growth is to "hold wealth constant" and follow the lives of people of a certain level, rich or poor, she explains. "Do we find education positively linked to the cultivation of new crops, or to the adoption of industrial innovations like knitting frames or sewing machines? Or to the acquisition of 'contemporary' goods such as cottons or coffee cups? Or to female labour force participation or involvement in the credit market?"

The team will also ask whether more highly educated women had fewer children – enabling them to invest more in those they had – as well as what aspect of education helped people engage more with productive and innovative activities. Was it, for instance, literacy, numeracy, book ownership, years of schooling? Was there a threshold level – a tipping point – that needed to be reached to affect economic performance?

Ogilvie hopes to start finding answers to these questions over the next two years. One thing is already clear, she says: the relationship between education and economic growth is far from straightforward.

"German-speaking central Europe is an excellent laboratory for testing theories of economic growth," she explains. "We know that literacy rates and book ownership were high and yet the region remained poor. We also know that local guilds and merchant associations were powerful and resisted changes that threatened their monopolies. Entrenched village oligarchies opposed disruptive innovations and blocked labour migration.

"Early findings suggest that the potential benefits of education for the economy can be held back by other barriers, and this has implications for today," she says. "Huge amounts are spent improving education in developing countries but this spending can fail to deliver economic growth if restrictions block people – especially women and the poor – from using their education in economically productive ways. If economic institutions are poorly set up, for instance, education can't lead to growth."

Ogilvie also hopes to dig deeper into which aspects of education matter. "We feel intuitively that the answer to the famous question posed by Tolstoy – 'Can there be two opinions on the advantage of education?' – is the one that Tolstoy gives: 'If it's a good thing for you, it's a good thing for everyone'.

"But while some types of schooling just benefit the providers or the authorities, other types make kids happier, increase their productivity, maximise impact on people's wellbeing and benefit the wider society."

Ogilvie believes the data will contain answers, and says: "I look at what we've amassed and I realise that I'm going to be working on these inventories for the rest of my life… I can think of much worse fates."

Explore further: 300 years of list-making

Related Stories

300 years of list-making

May 23, 2011

Personal inventories spanning three centuries are helping researchers unlock the mysteries of how economies edge towards growth and prosperity.

The fifty-percenters: the economic value of education

June 25, 2018

Almost half of young people in the UK now go to university. Who gets in – and what and where they study – affects a person's place in society and their future earnings, as well as the skills available to the job market. ...

For Americans, understanding money eases old age anxiety

February 2, 2018

A new household economics study from Hiroshima University suggests that financially literate people are more capable of accumulating wealth and worrying less about life in old age. This study is the first of its kind to examine ...

Recommended for you

Solving the mystery of an unusual medieval text

July 20, 2018

When historian Rowan Dorin first stepped onto the Stanford campus in early 2017, he made it a habit to visit Green Library every week to dig through its collection of medieval documents and objects.

4 comments

Adjust slider to filter visible comments by rank

Display comments: newest first

rrwillsj
3 / 5 (2) Jul 03, 2018
Well, several of the overlooked advantages to having fewer children would be first, survival. For the women bearing children. Each pregnancy was a potential death sentence.

More time between pregnancies meant more time for women to physically recover and rebuild their stamina for the next event.

Fewer children, meant more food for each child. More time available for the parents to raise and educate each child. More social resources such as education, health care, job opportunities for each child.

Sort of off the cuff and only peripheral to this article. Is what a crying shame it was, when most of England's tally sticks were burned as obsolete rubbish.

Those were a useful economic record carelessly destroyed. That could have helped to resolve some of the more obscure personal parts of British history,
Mayday
5 / 5 (2) Jul 03, 2018
There's a strong subtext here about governing bodies holding back growth due to their being driven to preserve the status quo.
rrwillsj
1 / 5 (1) Jul 03, 2018
Mayday, you bring up a very good point. Those satisfied with their lives and their station in life could be very reactionary.

The complexity comes in, when the investors in an enterprise expect steady growth in production to feed their never satisfied appetite for increasing ROI.

Upseting the Middle Managers complacency by rocking their boat of bureaucratic inertia.

From below you get Canuts & Luddites desperate to protect what little skilled work they were trained for. From being nade obsolete by new techniques & new technology. Overturning generations of isolated communitarian tribalism.

A lot of guys say they dream of throwing an axe over their shoulder and marching off into the wilderness to live as Thoreau did. To quote Robert Heinlein "Who made your axe?"

There ain't no Shakers left. All those orphans, abandons & runaways they took in? To feed & clothe, shelter & educate. As soon as any of those kids were big enough? They were gone.
RealScience
1 / 5 (1) Jul 04, 2018
@rrwillsj - well-thought posts.
But one in six children that the Shakers adopted became Shakers as adults, which was roughly enough to sustain them (although slowly shrinking as the economy improved) ... until laws were passed that banned religious orders from adopting children.

Please sign in to add a comment. Registration is free, and takes less than a minute. Read more

Click here to reset your password.
Sign in to get notified via email when new comments are made.