Paying for Donor Organs Could Drastically Increase Availability

Dec 11, 2007

Economic analysis suggests that healthy young donors in economies like that in the U.S. that place them at low-risk for post-surgical death would sell a kidney or a portion of a liver at prices that would drastically increase the number of those organs available for transplant and increase transplant cost by only 12 percent.

In a study published recently in the Journal of Economic Perspectives, economist Julio Elias of the University at Buffalo and Gary S. Becker of the University of Chicago, argue that "the use of monetary incentives would increase the supply of organs for transplant sufficiently to eliminate the very large queues in organ markets, and the suffering and deaths of many of those waiting, without increasing the total cost of transplant surgery by a large percent."

The study may be found online at the journal's Web site: www.aeaweb.org/jep/ .

Putting kidneys and other organs on the market may seem like the proposal straight from the cold heart of a free-market economist, but Elias notes that 18 Americans die every day -- more than 6,500 a year -- awaiting transplants.

"Although the number of kidneys, livers and other organs available for transplant has grown rapidly," he says, "the number of people awaiting transplants at any given time -- 97,000 -- has grown even more quickly."

"When an economist sees a persistent gap between supply and demand -- as in the demand for and supply of organs for transplants -- the next step is usually to look for the obstacles to market equilibrium," says Elias, assistant professor of economics in the UB College of Arts and Sciences.

"In the case of the market for transplantable organs," Elias says, "the obstacles are obvious. Very few countries allow the use of monetary incentives to acquire organs from either living donors or cadavers."

Although previous authors have discussed using monetary incentives to increase cadaveric organ donations, Elias and Becker stress the potential for eliciting more donations from living donors of kidneys and sections and livers, for example. Their collection, they say, is in several respects less subject to abuse and corruption than the collection of organs from cadavers.

Elias points out that the number of potential useable organs, especially from living donors, is very large compared to the number of transplants needed. The present system blocks almost all of this potential supply, however, by disallowing payments for organs although such financial incentives would attract enough live donors to close the gap between supply and demand.

"Donating an organ for transplantation," the paper acknowledges, "may affect an individual's quality of life, risk of mortality and ability to perform market and non-market activities for some period of time after the surgery."

Building on the value of statistical life, a measure that summarizes tradeoffs between monetary wealth and fatal safety risks, and other parts of economic analysis, the authors compute how much additional income or market consumption an individual will require to be indifferent as to the question of selling an organ or not.

Their analysis suggests that in the U.S, a payment of $15,200 per kidney, as a case in point, to a healthy live donor would significantly increase the pool of transplantable kidneys and eliminate the large queues in the market for kidney transplants.

Payment for organs, whether from live donors or cadavers, has been criticized on several grounds, among them the immorality of commodifying body parts, the likelihood that the poor would be the most likely donors and the possibility of reckless or impulsive donations.

The authors argue that paying for organs that save lives is no less moral than paying surrogate mothers for the use of their wombs or paying market wages to attract an army, which, they note, commodifies a recruit's entire body.

The organs of low-income persons who are sick are likely to be rejected, they say, so live donors would likely come from among the healthy poor and middle classes. They argue that poor individuals should not be deprived of revenue that could be highly useful to them, especially when their organs might save the lives of persons who are in desperate need.

Reckless or impulsive donations, say Elias and Becker, can be mitigated by requiring that donors be given written and verbal information about the risks posed by the surgery as well as afterwards. They also should be given a "cooling off" period, say the researchers, that is long enough for potential donors to seriously consider their decision.

Source: University at Buffalo

Explore further: French hospital plans wine bar to cheer patients' last days

add to favorites email to friend print save as pdf

Related Stories

Rosetta measures comet's temperature

1 hour ago

(Phys.org) —ESA's Rosetta spacecraft has made its first temperature measurements of its target comet, finding that it is too hot to be covered in ice and must instead have a dark, dusty crust.

Apple closes acquisition of Beats music

1 hour ago

Apple said Friday it closed its $3 billion deal for Beats, the high-end audio equipment and streaming music service, a tie-up that could allow the iPhone maker to reach new audiences.

Recommended for you

Exploring 3-D printing to make organs for transplants

Jul 30, 2014

Printing whole new organs for transplants sounds like something out of a sci-fi movie, but the real-life budding technology could one day make actual kidneys, livers, hearts and other organs for patients ...

High frequency of potential entrapment gaps in hospital beds

Jul 30, 2014

A survey of beds within a large teaching hospital in Ireland has shown than many of them did not comply with dimensional standards put in place to minimise the risk of entrapment. The report, published online in the journal ...

Key element of CPR missing from guidelines

Jul 29, 2014

Removing the head tilt/chin lift component of rescue breaths from the latest cardiopulmonary resuscitation (CPR) guidelines could be a mistake, according to Queen's University professor Anthony Ho.

User comments : 0